most of you might not be interested in the full article, then read the blog following this one which will give you some insights to the above topics with the subject.
Hoisington Investment Management
Quarterly Review and Outlook
Third Quarter 2012
Growth Recession
Entering the final quarter of the year, domestic and global
economic conditions are extremely fragile. Across the globe, countries
are in outright recession, and in some instances where aggregate growth
is holding above the zero line, manufacturing sectors are contracting.
The only issue left to determine is the degree of the downturn
underway. International trade is declining, so weaknesses in different
parts of the world are reinforcing domestic deteriorations in economies
continents away. With this global slump at hand, a highly relevant
question is whether the U.S. can escape a severe recession in light of
the following:
a) the U.S. manufacturing sector that paced domestic economic
growth over the past three years has lapsed into recession;
b) real income and the personal saving rate have been slumping in the face of an interim upturn in inflation, and
c) aggregate over-indebtedness, which is the dominant negative
force in the economy, has continued to move upward in concert with
flagging economic activity.
New government initiatives have been announced, particularly by
central banks, in an attempt to counteract deteriorating economic
conditions. These latest programs in the U.S. and Europe are similar to
previous efforts. While prices for risk assets have improved,
governments have not been able to address underlying debt imbalances.
Thus, nothing suggests that these latest actions do anything to change
the extreme over-indebtedness of major global economies.
To avoid recession in the U.S., the Federal Reserve embarked on
open-ended quantitative easing (QE3). Importantly, the enactment of
QE3 is a tacit admission by the Fed that earlier efforts failed, but
this action will also fail to bring about stronger economic growth.
Commodity Market Reactions
Commodity markets have risen in reaction to the Federal
Reserve’s liquidity injections into the banking sector (Table 1). From
the time the press reported that the Fed was moving toward QE1 & QE2
commodity prices surged. During QE1 & QE2 wholesale gasoline
prices jumped 30% and 37%, respectively, and the Goldman Sachs Commodity
Food Index (GSCI-Food) rose 7% and 22%, respectively. From the time
the press reported that the Fed was moving toward QE3, both gasoline and
the GSCI Food index jumped by 19%, through the end of the 3rd quarter.
Two theoretical considerations account for the rise in
commodity prices during QE3. The first is the expectations effect.
When the Fed says they want higher inflation, the initial reaction of
the markets is to “go with”, rather than fight the Fed. The second
linkage, which is the expanded availability of funds used for collateral
(margin), was identified and subsequently confirmed by Newedge
economist, Dr. Rod McKnew, who stated, “In a world of advanced
derivatives, high cash balances are not required to take speculative
positions. All that is required is that margin requirements be
satisfied.” Thus, when the Fed massively expanded reserve balances in
QE1 and QE2, margin risk was minimized for those market participants who
wished to take positions consistent with the Fed’s goal of higher
inflation, and who had either direct or indirect access to the Fed’s
hugely inflated reserve balances. The Apr
il 22,
2011 issue of Grant’s Interest Rate Observer documented support for
McKnew’s insight. They asked Darrell Duffie, the Dean Witter
Distinguished Professor of Finance at the Graduate School of Business at
Stanford University, whether excess reserves could serve as collateral
for futures and derivatives transactions. Dr. Duffie’s answer was
“acceptable collateral is a matter of private contract, but reserve
deposits are virtually always acceptable.”
Devastation for Households
The unintended consequence of these Federal Reserve actions,
however, is to actually slow economic activity. The CPI rose
significantly in QE1 and QE2 (Chart 1). These price increases had a
devastating effect on worker's incomes (Chart 2). Wages did not
immediately respond to commodity price changes; therefore, there was an
approximate 3% decline in real average hourly earnings in both
instances. It is true that stock prices also rose along with commodity
prices (S&P plus 36% and 24%, respectively, in QE1 and QE2).
However, median households hold a small portion of equities, and thus
received minimal wealth benefit.
Wealth Effect
Despite the miserable economic results in QE1 and QE2, we now
have QE3. Fed Chair Ben Bernanke and other Fed advocates believe the
“wealth effect” of QE3 will bring life to the economy. The economics
profession has explored this issue in detail. Sydney Ludvigson and
Charles Steindel in How Important is the Stock Market Effect on Consumption
in the FRBNY Economic Policy Review, July 1999 write: “We find, as
expected, a positive connection between aggregate wealth changes and
aggregate spending. Spending growth in recent years has surely been
augmented by market gains, but the effect is found to be rather unstable
and hard to pin down. The contemporaneous response of consumption
growth to an unexpected change in wealth is uncertain, and the response
appears very short-lived.” More recently, David Backus, economic
professor at New York University found that the wealth effect is not
observable, at least
for
changes in home or equity wealth.
A 2011 study in Applied Economic Letters entitled, Financial Wealth Effect: Evidence from Threshold Estimation
by Sherif Khalifa, Ousmane Seck and Elwin Tobing found “a threshold
income level of almost $130,000, below which the financial wealth effect
is insignificant, and above which the effect is 0.004.” This means a $1
rise in wealth would, in time, boost consumption by less than one-half
penny.
These three studies show that the impact of wealth on spending
is miniscule—indeed, “nearly not observable.” How the Fed expects the
U.S. to gain any economic traction from higher stock prices when rising
commodity prices are curtailing real income and spending is puzzling.
This is particularly relevant when econometricians have estimated that
for every dollar of gained real income, consumption will rise by about
70 cents. Conversely, the Fed actions are causing real incomes to
decline, which has a 70-cent negative impact on spending for every
dollar loss. Compare that with the 0.004 positive impact on spending
for every one-dollar increase in wealth. Former Fed Chairman, Paul
Volcker, summarized the new Fed initiative as sufficiently and
succinctly as anyone when he stated that another round of QE3 “is
understandable, but it will fail to fix the problem.”
An International Corollary
The unintended consequences of QE3 could also serve to worsen
and undermine global economic conditions already under considerable
duress. When the Fed actions lead to higher food and fuel prices, the
shock wave reverberates around the world, with many foreign economies
being hit adversely. When prices of basic necessities rise, the
greatest burden is on those with the lowest incomes since more of their
budget is allocated to the basic necessities such as food and fuel.
Thus, a jump in daily essentials has a more profound negative impact on
living standards in economies with lower levels of real per capita
income.
Can the Fed Create Demand?
Can all the trillions of dollars of reserves being added to the
banking system move the economy forward enough to eventually create a
higher level of aggregate spending? Our analysis of the aggregate
demand curve and its determinants indicate they cannot. The question is
whether monetary actions can shift this aggregate demand (AD) curve out
to the right from AD0 to AD1 (Chart 3). If this were possible, then
indeed the economy would shift to a higher level of prices and real GDP.
The AD curve is equal to planned expenditures for nominal GDP
since every point on the curve is equal to the aggregate price level
(measured on the vertical axis of the graph), multiplied by real GDP
(measured on the horizontal axis of the graph). We know that GDP is
equal to money times its turnover or velocity, which is called the
equation of exchange as developed by Irving Fisher (Nominal GDP = M*V).
Deconstructing this formula, M (or M2) is comprised of the
monetary base (currency plus reserves) times the money multiplier (m).
The Federal Reserve has control over the monetary base since its balance
sheet is the dominant component of the monetary base. However, the Fed
does not directly control the money supply. The decisions of the
depository institutions and the non-bank public determine the money
multiplier (m). M2 thus equals the monetary base multiplied by the
money multiplier. The monetary base, also referred to as high powered
money, has exploded from $800 billion in 2008, to $2.6 trillion
currently, but the money multiplier has collapsed from 9.3 to 3.9 (Chart
4). Therefore, the money supply has risen significantly less than the
increase in the Fed’s balance sheet, with the result that neither rapid
gains in real GDP nor inflation were achieved. Indeed, with the
exception of transitory episodes, inflation re
mains
subdued and the gain in GDP in the three years of this expansion was the
worst of any recovery period since World War II.
The other element that is required for the Fed to shift the
aggregate demand curve outward is the velocity or turnover of money over
which they also have no control. During all of the Fed actions since
2008 the velocity of money has plummeted and now stands at a five decade
low (Chart 5).
The consequence of the Fed’s lack of control over the money
multiplier and velocity is apparent. The monetary base has surged 3.3
times in size since QE1. Nominal GDP, however, has grown only at an
annual rate of 3%. This suggests they have not been able to shift the
aggregate demand curve outward. Nor, with these constraints, will they
be any more successful in shifting that curve under the present
open-ended QE3. Increased aggregate demand and thus rising inflation is
not on the horizon.
[For a more complete discussion of the complexities of the
movement of the aggregate supply and aggregate demand curves please see
the APPENDIX.]
Treasury Bonds
As commodity prices rose initially in all the QE programs,
long-term Treasury bond yields also increased. However, those higher
yields eventually reversed and generally continued to ratchet downward,
reaching near record lows. The current Fed actions may be politically
necessary due to numerous demands for them to act to improve the clearly
depressed state of economic conditions. However, these policies will
prove to be unproductive. Economic fundamentals will not improve until
the extreme over-indebtedness of the U.S. economy is addressed, and this
is in the realm of fiscal, not monetary policy. It would be more
beneficial for the Fed to sit on the sidelines and try to put pressure
on the fiscal authorities to take badly needed actions rather than do
additional harm. Until the excessive debt issues are addressed, the
multi-year trend in inflation, and thus the long Treasury bond yields
will remain downward.
APPENDIX
One of the most important concepts in macroeconomics is
aggregate demand (AD) and aggregate supply (AS) analysis – a highly
attractive approach that is neither Keynesian, monetarist, Austrian, nor
any other individual school, but can be used to illustrate all of their
main propositions. However, before detailing the broader
macroeconomics associated with the movement of the AD and AS curves, it
is important to understand microeconomic supply and demand curves. This
can best be illustrated through the recent impact the Fed’s decisions
had on commodity prices. In the commodity market, like individual
markets in general, the demand curve is downward sloping, the supply
curve is upward sloping, and where they intersect determines the price
of the commodity and the quantity supplied/demanded. The micro-demand
curve slopes downward because as the price of an item rises, the
quantity demanded falls due to income and substitution effects (
buyers
can shift to a substitute product). The micro-supply curve slopes
upward since producers will sell more at higher prices than lower ones.
Both supply and demand schedules are influenced by expectation,
fundamental, and liquidity considerations. When the Fed says that they
want faster inflation and that they are going to take steps to achieve
this objective, both economic theory and historical experiences indicate
that commodity prices will rise, at least transitorily (as seen with
the surge in commodity prices after the announcement of QE1, QE2 and
QE3). Information and liquidity available to the buyers is also
available to the suppliers, so by saying faster inflation is ahead,
suppliers are encouraged to reduce or withhold current production or
inventories, moving the supply curve inward. Thus, in the commodity
market, the Fed action spurs an outward shift in the micro-demand curve
along with an inward shift of the micro-supply curve, producing higher
prices and lower quantities. These microeconomic developments transmit
to the broader economy, which we will now trace through A
D and
AS curves.
The AD curve slopes downward and indicates the amount of real
GDP that would be purchased at each aggregate price level (Chart 6).
Aggregate demand varies inversely with the price level, so if the price
level moves upward from P0 to P1, real GDP declines from Y0 to Y1. When
the price level rises, real wages, real money balances and net exports
worsen, thereby reducing real GDP. The rationale for the downward
sloping AD curve is thus quite different from the sloping of the
micro-demand curve since substitution effects are not possible when
dealing with aggregate prices. In order to improve real GDP with a
rising price level, the AD curve would need to be shifted outward and to
the right (from AD0 to AD1). And as detailed in the letter, the Fed is
not capable of shifting the entire AD curve.
The AS curve slopes upward and indicates the quantity of GDP
supplied at various price levels. The positive correlation between
price and output in micro and macroeconomics is the same since the AS
curve is the sum of all supply curves across all individual markets.
When Fed policy announcements shock commodity markets, the AS curve
shifts inward and to the left (from AS0 to AS1). This immediately
causes a reduction in real GDP (the difference between Y0 and Y1) as the
price increases by the difference between P0 and P1 (also Chart 6).
Furthermore, as discussed in the letter, lower GDP as a result of higher
prices reduces the demand for labor and widens the output gap, setting
in motion a negative spiral.
For Fed policy to improve real GDP, actions must be taken that
either (1) shift the entire demand curve outward (to the right), or (2)
do not cause an inward shift of the AS curve that induces an adverse
movement along the AD curve. Accordingly, the Fed is without options to
improve the pace of economic activity.
No comments:
Post a Comment